Hive Developer logo

Hive Developer Portal

RC Bandwidth Parameters

Analyze the dynamics of the resource budget pool.

Parameters

Each pool has its own values of the following constants:

Computed values

Let us analyze the dynamics of the resource budget pool as outlined here with an eye to establishing values of the parameters.

Setting p_0

Let p(x) be the RC cost curve, p(x) = A / (B + x).

Let’s denote as p_0 the value of p(0), which is of course p_0 = A / B. In other words,p_0 is the price when there are no resources in the pool. Let’s set up a worst-case scenario:

Then we can solve for p_0 in terms of t_drain and the budget:

global_rc_capacity + global_rc_regen * drain_time = p_0 * budget * drain_time
p_0 = (global_rc_capacity + global_rc_regen * drain_time) / (budget * drain_time)

Suppose drain_time = 1 hour. Then the interpretation of this equation is that, in an hour, users in the aggregate can only muster RC equal to their RC capacity plus an hour’s worth of RC regen, call this much RC rc_1h. If we say this RC “should” be just enough to pay for res_1h, 1 hour’s worth of a single resource (say, an hour’s worth of history bytes). That implies a resource price of rc_1h / res_1h, which is the price we set the value of p_0 to.

If we substitute for global_rc_capacity and simplify, we get an alternative expression for p_0 which may be useful for some analysis:

p_0 = (global_rc_capacity + global_rc_regen * drain_time) / (budget * drain_time)
    = (global_rc_regen * rc_regen_time + global_rc_regen * drain_time) / (budget * drain_time)
    = (global_rc_regen / budget) * (1 + rc_regen_time / drain_time)

The first multiplicative term, global_rc_regen / budget, is the balanced budget price which would cause spending to match outflow; let us say p_bb = global_rc_regen / budget. This is the equilibrium price if users have no reserves and spend all RC’s on this resource. This is multiplied by a multiplier which represents the temporary level the price can rise to, which is ultimately unsustainable due to finite reserves.

Setting B

What about the constant B? When x is much smaller than B:

When x is much larger than B the opposite is true:

So while p(x) is never fully elastic or inelastic, you may think of B as being near the “midpoint” of the “transition” from almost perfectly inelastic (for small x) to almost perfectly elastic (for large x). This makes sense, since a perfectly elastic price is desirable (when possible) but unstable when the pool goes to zero (a halving of the pool results in the doubling of the price, meaning the price “doubles infinite times” as the pool goes toward zero, “halving infinite times”).

Where should this transition occur? The simple answer is a small fraction of the pool’s equilibrium size at no load, say 1%, or perhaps 1/128.

Inelasticity proof

A more rigorous way to say that p(x) is (almost) inelastic is that, for any small value , there exists some x small enough such that, for any small value δ, we have f(x) / f((1+δ)*x) < 1+δ*∊. (This can be interpreted as saying the percentage change in f(x) in response to a percentage change in x dies out as x →0⁺.)

To prove this, set x = B*∊. Then:

f(x) / f((1+δ)*x) = (A / (B+x)) / (A / (B+(1+δ)*x))
   = (B+x+δ*x) / (B+x)
   = 1 + δ*x / (B+x)
   < 1 + δ*x / B
   = 1 + δ*∊

Elasticity proof

TODO: State/prove similar condition for elasticity case.

Decay rate

Let τ be the time constant for the decay rate. (The decay constant is proportional to the half-life.) The value of τ is essentially how much time it takes for the system to “forget” about past non-usage, and places a “soft limit” on the possibility of a very long burst of very high activity being allowed as a result of “saving up” months or years worth of inactivity. The value of τ is per-resource, and we’ve determined that resources should have short-term and long-term versions with different τ values. For short-term τ value, I recommend 1 hour. For the long-term τ value, I recommend 15 days.

If Δt time passes, then the exponential decay step of updating the pool should be pool -= Δt * pool / τ.

The no-load equilibrium pool size then occurs when Δt * pool_eq / τ = Δt * budget_per_sec, or pool_eq = τ * budget_per_sec.

Discount term

Above, we set implicitly the largest (zero-stockpile) price p_0 based on drain_time. It may also be useful to set the smallest possible price p_eq to something other than the value implied by the above equations. To do this, we can simply shift the curve downward by a factor of D, and scale the curve up so p(0) = p_0.

To elaborate:

First, define p(x) with discount term D such that

p(x) = (A / (B + x)) - D

Then set B = inelasticity_threshold * pool_eq. For A and D we have two equations in two unknowns:

p_0 = (A / B) - D
p_eq = (A / (B + pool_eq)) - D

Solve both equations for A, set the two expressions equal to each other, and solve for D:

A = B*(p_0 + D) = (p_eq+D)*(B+pool_eq)
-> B*p_0 + B*D = B*p_eq + B*D + p_eq*pool_eq + D*pool_eq
-> B*(p_0 - p_eq) - p_eq*pool_eq = D*pool_eq
-> (B / pool_eq)*(p_0 - p_eq) - p_eq = D